Pages

Thursday, August 15, 2019

Analysis five forces of framework

If you order your custom term paper from our custom writing service you will receive a perfectly written assignment on analysis five forces of framework. What we need from you is to provide us with your detailed paper instructions for our experienced writers to follow all of your specific writing requirements. Specify your order details, state the exact number of pages required and our custom writing professionals will deliver the best quality analysis five forces of framework paper right on time.


Our staff of freelance writers includes over 120 experts proficient in analysis five forces of framework, therefore you can rest assured that your assignment will be handled by only top rated specialists. Order your analysis five forces of framework paper at affordable prices !


Page 1


This paper seeks to contribute thinking on how the intellectual foundations of


antitrust might be updated, based on a large body of theoretical and empirical research on


company strategy, competition, and economic development. The aim is to outline a new


direction for antitrust that can be incorporated into government policy and legal practice


and pursued in litigation and legislation, both in the United States and internationally.


This new thinking sets forth productivity growth as the basic goal of antitrust policy, and


employs tools like industry structure analysis and locational analysis to evaluate potential


impacts on competition. While there appears to be broad consensus on how to deal with


much anticompetitive behavior such as deceptive practices and cartel formation, the


current fault line in antitrust is the treatment of mergers. This paper therefore focuses on


the evaluation of mergers, though the same framework can be applied to evaluating joint


ventures, other combinations, and other competitive practices. Finally, it should be noted


that this paper is concerned principally with the content of antitrust, not the many


important issues involved in structuring antitrust agencies and designing processes of


enforcement.


Section II argues that the true benefits of healthy competition are not fully articulated


in much antitrust analysis. By linking competition to a nation's standard of living


through productivity growth, it becomes apparent that far more is at stake in protecting


competition than short-term consumer welfare defined by price-cost margins. Empirical


evidence is provided to highlight the importance of protecting the vitality of competition.


Furthermore, it is argued that local competition within a nation is particularly crucial for


competitiveness, even in the era of globalization.


Section III proposes that productivity growth become the new standard for antitrust,


and reassesses the hierarchy of antitrust goals accordingly. Since healthy competition


will foster productivity growth, antitrust must be equipped with adequate tools and


frameworks for evaluating the health of competition. Yet frameworks broader than


current practices resting in relevant market definitions and ability to elevate price above


cost are required. So called "five forces" analysis is offered as a broader tool for


evaluating overall industry competition, while the diamond framework for locational


competitiveness is offered for evaluating the health of local competition.


In Section IV, we turn to the analysis of mergers, outlining a three-level merger


evaluation process that incorporates the productivity growth standard and the tools for


evaluating the health of competition mentioned above. Section V offers a short case


study of a merger evaluation, using the new procedure. Finally, Section VI addresses


some recent issues more specific to U.S. antitrust policy.


The essential role of competition and antitrust policy in competitiveness is evident in


recent research on industry competition and economic development. My conviction from


working both with companies and public policymakers in many countries is that open


competition, stimulated by strict antitrust enforcement, is essential not only to national


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page


prosperity, but to the health of companies themselves. Yet antitrust seems to be drifting.


Antitrust policy is being challenged by skeptics who are mounting attacks on the need for


antitrust under the guise of globalization or the requirements of the "new economy."


Also, the theoretical and empirical literature on competition has moved beyond seller


concentration, price-cost margins, and other ideas central to current enforcement.1


It is an important moment to reinvigorate antitrust. Not to say that antitrust


enforcement has been lax, nor that skilled practitioners have not been able to apply the


law with great sophistication. However, recent court rulings and public debate suggest


that the foundations of antitrust theory and practice are wearing thin. The goals of


antitrust and its link to society's goals are often not convincingly articulated. The


benefits of competition that underpin antitrust have not been made clear, and the tools for


measuring impacts on competition are frequently controversial. Too often the discussion


between business and government in antitrust proceedings concerns arcane matters such


as HHI that erodes the legitimacy of antitrust with the private sector. By relying too


heavily on narrowly conceived consumer welfare theory, antitrust analysis may be


overlooking some of the most important benefits of competition for society. Antitrust is


not living up to its full promise in deterring behavior that is not in society's interest.


My aim here is not to offer a comprehensive treatise, settle all of the issues raised, nor


do justice to the scholarly or practitioner literature. Instead, the intention is to stimulate


further dialogue and analysis.


1 See Sections II and III.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page


II. COMPETITION, COMPETITIVENESS, AND STANDARD OF


LIVING THE ROLE OF ANTITRUST


II.1. Competition, productivity growth, and standard of living


The stated role of antitrust policy is to promote and protect competition in the name


of consumer welfare. Yet the rationale is frequently unclear, misunderstood, or too


narrow in scope. While protecting short-run consumer welfare measured by price-cost


margins is undeniably important, the benefits of healthy competition are in fact broader


and more essential to consumers and to society. The fundamental benefit of competition


is to drive productivity growth through innovation, where innovation is defined broadly


to include not only products, but also processes and methods of management.


Productivity growth is central because it is the single most important determinant of longterm


consumer welfare and a nation's standard of living.


The underpinnings of economic prosperity are becoming better understood as a result


of continuing research. While sound macroeconomic policies and stable political and


legal institutions represent important preconditions for prosperity and competitiveness,


they are necessary but not sufficient conditions for a prosperous economy. Prosperity is


actually generated at the microeconomic levelin the ability of firms to create valuable


goods and services productively that will support high wages and high returns to capital.


The goal of economic development is to achieve long term, sustainable improvement


in a nations standard of living, which can be approximated by per capita national income


(GDP per capita). Per capita income is determined by the productivity of a nations


economy, where productivity is defined as the total value of the goods and services


(products) produced per unit of the nations human, capital and physical resources. A


nation's overall productivity is composed of the productivity of its firms, both those


involved in traded industries and those involved in purely local commerce. The crucial


issue, then, is how to create the conditions for rapid and sustained productivity growth in


a nations firms.


Since the seminal contributions of Schumpeter (14), Solow (156) and Abramovitz


(156), it is widely understood that the only means of achieving sustained productivity


growth in an economy is through innovation.4 Innovation provides products and services


M.E. Porter, The Microeconomic Foundations of Economic Development, in The Global


Competitiveness Report 18, 8 (Geneva World Economic Forum, 18). See also M.E. Porter,


"Attitudes, Values, Beliefs, and the Microeconomics of Prosperity," in Culture Matters How Values


Shape Human Progress (L.E. Harrison & S.P. Huntington eds., 000).


While income is the best available measure, other things contribute to national standard of living


besides wages and returns to capital, such as the quality of health care, the absence of extreme income


inequality, and environmental quality.


4 J. Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy (d ed. 14); R. Solow, "Technical Change


and the Aggregate Production Function,"Review of Economics and Statistics 1 (157); R. Solow,


"A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth," 70 Quarterly Journal of Economics 65 (156);


(continue)


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 4


of ever-increasing consumer value, as well as ways of producing products more


efficiently, both of which contribute directly to productivity.


Innovation, in this broad sense, is driven by competition. While technological


innovation is the result of a variety of factors, there is no doubt that healthy competition


is an essential part. One need only review the dismal innovation record of countries


lacking strong competition to be convinced of this fact. Vigorous competition in a


supportive business environment is the only path to sustained productivity growth, and


therefore to long term economic vitality.


Productivity growth, then, is the missing, unstated link between competition and


national standard of living. This provides the soundest explanation for why antitrust must


protect competition it is the key to a nation's economic prosperity. Productivity growth


thinking also makes it clear that the focus of antitrust thinking should be on the long-term


trajectory of product value and price, not just current consumer welfare measured by


short-run prices. The following sections outline how the central role of productivity in


development and societal welfare can be applied to antitrust and competition policy.


II.. Importance of Industry Competition empirical evidence


Recent empirical findings verify the importance of competition to raising and


maintaining standard of living. This evidence squares well with my own experience.


Competition really matters, in the new economy and the old economy, and in all types of


countries.


One body of empirical evidence comes from The Global Competitiveness Report


000, an annual study of competitiveness in 58 countries including all the OECD


countries as well as many developing countries.5 Data from the report are drawn from a


survey of more than 4,000 corporate and other leaders, including a representative sample


from each country. The survey is qualitative, but represents a large body of expert


opinion on important dimensions of economic policy, for which there are no quantitative


measures.


Figure 1 reproduces some of the statistical findings from the Report. For all three


years in which this analysis has been conducted, the effectiveness of antitrust policy6


proves to be one of the variables with the strongest positive association with the variation


in GDP per capita across countries. This holds even in the subsample of developing


(continued)


M. Abramowitz, "Resource and Output Trends in the United States since 1870," 46 American


Economic Review 5 (156).


5 M.E. Porter, "The Current Competitiveness Index Measuring the Economic Foundations of


Prosperity," in The Global Competitiveness Report 000 (Geneva World Economic Forum, 000).


6 In id. at 1, the effectiveness of antitrust policy was measured in a survey by responses to question


10.14, The anti-monopoly policy effectively promotes competition, using a scale from 1-7, strongly


disagree to strongly agree.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 5


economies, an indication that antitrust is also important for poor countries, rather than


just a luxury needed only in wealthy ones. The report also includes a survey question


about the intensity of local competition. While the question is imperfect because of


possible ambiguities in its interpretation by respondents, it also has a highly significant


positive association with GDP per capita.


Figure 1 Competition and Prosperity Findings from The Global Competitiveness


Report


Regression


Dependent Variable 14 -GDP per capita growth


Significance Adj R


Measure of National Business at 5% level


Environment


Intensity of local competition at 5% level .55


Effectiveness of Antitrust policy at 5% level .117


Regression


Dependent Variable 14 -GDP per capita growth


Significance Adj R


Measure of National Business at 5% level


Environment


Intensity of local competition at 5% level .55


Effectiveness of Antitrust policy at 5% level .117


Regression


Dependent Variable 1 GDP per capita


Significance Adj R


Measure of National Business at 5% level


Environment


Effectiveness of antitrust policy at 5% level .700


Intensity of local competition at 5% level .0


Regression


Dependent Variable 1 GDP per capita


Significance Adj R


Measure of National Business at 5% level


Environment


Effectiveness of antitrust policy at 5% level .700


Intensity of local competition at 5% level .0


"...countries where the intensity of competition is rising


showed by far the greatest improvement in GDP per capita."


Source M.E. Porter, "The Current Competitiveness Index Measuring the Microeconomic Foundations of


Prosperity", in The Global Competitiveness Report 000 (Geneva World Economic Forum, 000).


Turning to analysis of the rate of growth in GDP per capita, the effectiveness of


antitrust policy and the intensity of competition are again highly significant variables and


contribute substantially to explained variance. Note that the proportion of variance in


GDP per capita growth rate that can be explained is inherently less than for the level of


GDP, because growth in GDP is more sensitive to a wide variety of shocks and shortterm


macroeconomic influences. We find that the competition/antitrust policy measures


are as or more associated with prosperity as transportation infrastructure, telecom


infrastructure, IT readiness, and the like. In a first difference analysis, countries where


the intensity of competition is rising showed registered the greatest improvement in GDP


per capita. All these findings are consistent competition and a vigorous antitrust policy


are strongly associated with national prosperity.


This research provides some positive evidence of the importance of strong antitrust


for prosperity. There is also ample negative evidence to be cited. For example, Japan is


a country with a history of weak antitrust enforcement, legal cartels, and extensive


government-sponsored collaborative research projects among companies. During the


height of the Japanese economic miracle, the case of Japan was a principal argument


advanced in the United States for weakening antitrust lawfor example, in allowing


potentially anticompetitive collaborative activity.7


7 M.E. Porter, H. Takeuchi & M. Sakakibara, Can Japan Compete? (000).


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 6


Yet one of the major findings of a recent book is the steep price that Japan has paid


for a lax antitrust policy.8 Our research revealed that weak antitrust enforcement did not


explain Japanese competitiveness, but was in fact an explanation for why certain


industries in Japan were uncompetitive. Industries where competition was limited by


Japanese government policy were uncompetitive. We also collected data on all the legal


cartels in post-World War II Japan, and found that the industries in which cartels


occurred were, with few exceptions, uncompetitive. We also collected data on all


government-sponsored cooperative research projects, which involved several if not most


industry competitors. We found that those industries in which cooperative research


projects occurred were no more likely than the average industry to be competitive, and


many cooperative research projects actually worked against industry competitiveness.


There have been many collaborative projects in the West involving multiple industry


competitors growing out of the efforts to emulate the Japanese case, such as the electric


vehicle project. With few if any exceptions, these have proven disappointing. The


notion that Japan was competitive because of weak antitrust is resoundingly rejected.


Figurehighlights some additional data drawn from our study of Japan. We


explored the relationship between the intensity of domestic competition and world export


share in a broad sample of Japanese industries. All of the industries considered were


global in scope. Industries able to command a high world export share were decreed to


be highly productive.


Instead of relying on market structure measures such as seller concentration to proxy


the intensity of competition, we used the extent of fluctuations in domestic market share


among leading firms over an 18-year period. The fluctuation in market share among


leading competitorscontrolling for outside shocksprovides a direct and far more


compelling indication of the intensity of competition. We found that domestic market


share variability was by far the most powerful influence on Japanese world export share,


dominating conventional measures of comparative advantage such as skilled labor


intensity and capital intensity. The intensity of competition at home, then, was the


strongest influence on Japanese competitiveness abroad. These statistical findings are


consistent with hundreds of industry case studies that have been conducted on the


determinants of competitiveness at the country level, as well as research on national and


regional economic development.10


Interestingly, we found that seller concentration had no significant relationship with


Japanese world export share.11 Nor was it significantly correlated with the extent of


8 Id. See also M. Sakakibara & M.E. Porter, "Competing at Home to Win Abroad Evidence from


Japanese Industry," 8 Review of Economics and Statistics 10 (001).


See generally R. Caves & M. Porter, "Market Structure, Oligopoly, and Stability of Market Shares," 6


Journal of Industrial Economics 8 (178). For a detailed application to Japan, including definitions,


sources of data, cause and effect issues, see Sakakibara & Porter, supra note 8.


10 See, e.g., "Clusters and Competition New agendas for Companies, Governments, and Institutions" in


M.E. Porter, On Competition (18), which contains an extensive bibliography.


11 Sakakibara & Porter, supra note 8.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 7


domestic market share fluctuations. These results are consistent with other research


which raises doubts about the use of seller concentration as a proxy for the vitality of


competition.1


FigureCompetition and International Competitiveness Evidence from Japanese


Industry


Competitiveness Competitiveness


Local Competition Local Competition


• Measured by World Export Share


• Measured by Fluctuations in


Domestic Market Share


Sakakibara/Porter


"We find a positive and highly


significant relationship between the


extent of market share fluctuations [a


measure of local rivalry] and trade


performance


Contrary to some popular views, our


results suggest that Japanese


competitiveness is associated with


home market competition, not


collusion, cartels, or government


intervention that stabilize it."


Source M. Sakakibara & M.E. Porter, "Competing at Home to Win Abroad Evidence from Japanese


Industry", 8 Review of Economics and Statistics 10, 18, 1 (May 001).


II.. Importance of Local Competition1 Externalities, cluster theory, and the link


between clusters and innovation


The Japanese research and other evidence suggest that, contrary to popular belief,


local competition matters in global industries. Even where firms compete across borders,


the configuration of locally based competitors and the vitality of competition in the local


market are crucial to productivity and competitiveness. Local competition creates


numerous positive externalities for industries and industry clusters, thus explaining its


significant impact on firm competitiveness.


Many industries can be considered global in competitive scope, which is often taken


to imply that a firm's location is of no importance to the health of competition. Yet the


actual distribution of firms belies this view. We observe a strong tendency for successful


1 See, e.g., K. Ewing, "The Soft Underbelly of Antitrust," Antitrust Report, Sept. 1 at ; B. Harris &


D. Smith, "The Merger Guidelines v. Economics A Survey of Economic Studies," Antitrust Report,


Sept. 1 at ; C. Weller, "An Evolution of the Merger-JV Guidelines The Productivity Paradigm


As A Positive Antitrust Policy for Competitiveness and Prosperity," American Bar Association,


Perspectives of the Task Force on Fundamental Theory (forthcoming, 001).


1 It should be noted that the term local can apply to geographic areas ranging from a small county to a


group of neighboring countries. The relevant economic area depends on geographic distance and the


scope of local externalities.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 8


firms in a particular industry to cluster in particular countries, often along with firms in


related industries. The schematic map of the U.S. clusters in figureshows that


geographic clustering can occur even in sub-national regions within countries. This


ubiquitous phenomenon reveals powerful insights into the role of location in healthy


competition.


FigureSelected Regional Clusters of Competitive U.S. Industries


Omaha


Telemarketing


Hotel Reservations


Credit Card Processing


Wisconsin / Iowa / Illinois


Agricultural Equipment


Detroit


Auto


Equipment


and Parts


Rochester


Imaging


Equipment


Western Massachusetts


Polymers


Boston


Mutual Funds


Biotechnology


Software and


Networking


Venture


Capital


Hartford


Insurance


Providence


Jewelry


Marine Equipment


New York City


Financial Services


Advertising


Publishing


Multimedia


Pennsylvania / New Jersey


Pharmaceuticals


North Carolina


Household Furniture


Synthetic Fibers


Hosiery


Dalton, Georgia


Carpets


South Florida


Health Technology


Computers


Nashville /


Louisville


Hospital


Management


Baton Rouge /


New Orleans


Specialty Foods


Southeast Texas


/ Louisiana


Chemicals


Dallas


Real Estate


Development


Wichita


Light Aircraft


Farm Equipment


Los Angeles Area


Defense Aerospace


Entertainment


Silicon Valley


Microelectronics


Biotechnology


Venture Capital


Cleveland / Louisville


Paints & Coatings


Pittsburgh


Advanced Materials


Energy


West Michigan


Office and Institutional


Furniture


Michigan


Clocks


Carlsbad


Golf Equipment


Minneapolis


Cardio-vascular


Equipment


and Services


Warsaw, Indiana


Orthopedic Devices


Colorado


Computer Integrated Systems / Programming


Engineering Services


Mining / Oil and Gas Exploration


Phoenix


Helicopters


Semiconductors


Electronic Testing Labs


Optics


Las Vegas


Amusement /


Casinos


Small Airlines


Oregon


Electrical Measuring


Equipment


Woodworking Equipment


Logging / Lumber


Supplies


Seattle


Aircraft Equipment and Design


Boat and Ship Building


Metal Fabrication


Boise


Sawmills


Farm Machinery


Firms cluster in particular locations not because of traditional comparative advantages


stemming from natural resources or pools of cheap labor. Rather, they obtain competitive


advantages by locating in areas benefiting from the strong presence of other firms in the


industry, firms in related industries, and the presence of specialized inputs, information,


and institutions. The explanation for geographic clustering is that local competition


provides an exceptional stimulus to productivity growth that is extremely valuable to


firms. The two major contributions of local competition are


1. Incentive and Informational Benefits The immediate presence of a rival


stimulates greater comparison, improvement, and upgrading versus competing


with a firm in a foreign country. Companies that compete at home are better


prepared to compete with foreign rivals abroad.


. Positive Externalities Geographic proximity of rivals generates otherwise


unattainable positive externalities, such as a specialized labor pools,


knowledge spillovers, specialized supplier formation, etc. discussed below.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page


The Positive Externalities of Local Rivalry. Competition creates positive externalities for


the local business environment that boost productivity for the entire industry, and often


for related and supporting industries in the same location as well. A group of competing


local rivals tends to spawn a base of local suppliers and providers of specialized support


services. This boosts productivity by reducing transactions costs, facilitating the


exchange of information, increasing flexibility, and speeding innovation. Local rivalry


also works to increase the local availability of specialized skills, infrastructure, scientific


and technical resources, and other assets and institutions that boost productivity and raise


the rate of productivity growth. As these externalities deepen, they can foster new entry


and spinoffs, coming full circle to reinforce local rivalry. Such externalities are what


give rise to what I term clusters, or geographic concentrations of interconnected


companies and institutions in a particular field.


California wine provides a good example of a cluster (see figure 4). There are


hundreds of wineries in California, but also thousands of independent growers of grapes.


All the inputs, production equipment, and services required to grow grapes and produce


wine are available locally. Local universities and other institutions provide ample skilled


labor and technological information. As a result, the productivity of California as a wineproducing


region in terms of yield per acre appears to be the highest in the world, and


firms command high prices per bottle for their premium-quality products. The rate of


productivity growth has been rapid, as California wine companies upgraded from jug


wine to super premium segments.


Figure 4 The California Wine Cluster


Educational, Research, & Trade


Organizations (e.g. Wine Institute,


UC Davis, Culinary Institutes)


Educational, Research, & Trade


Organizations (e.g. Wine Institute,


UC Davis, Culinary Institutes)


Growers/Vineyards Growers/Vineyards Wineries/Processing


Facilities


Wineries/Processing


Facilities


Grapestock Grapestock


Fertilizer, Pesticides,


Herbicides


Fertilizer, Pesticides,


Herbicides


Grape Harvesting


Equipment


Grape Harvesting


Equipment


Irrigation Technology Irrigation Technology


Winemaking


Equipment


Winemaking


Equipment


Barrels Barrels


Labels Labels


Bottles Bottles


Caps and Corks Caps and Corks


Public Relations and


Advertising


Public Relations and


Advertising


Specialized Publications


(e.g., Wine Spectator,


Trade Journal)


Specialized Publications


(e.g., Wine Spectator,


Trade Journal)


Food Cluster Food Cluster


Tourism Cluster Tourism Cluster California


Agricultural Cluster


California


Agricultural Cluster


State Government Agencies


(e.g., Select Committee on Wine


Production and Economy)


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 10


Source M.E. Porter, On Competition (18), at ch. 7.


Other well-known examples of U.S. clusters include the Silicon Valley IT cluster, the


Houston oil and gas cluster, and the Boston area biopharmaceuticals and mutual fund


clusters.


The Global Competitiveness Report includes measures of the quality and quantity of


local suppliers and, in the 000 report the extent of clusters in a national economy. All


three variables have a strong positive association with GDP per capita.


Taking into account the essential benefits of local competition leads to the conclusion


that antitrust analysis should weigh not just the generalized benefits of rivalry for


productivity growth but also the systemic benefits of local rivalry. When local rivalry is


muted, a nation pays a double price. Not only will companies face less pressure to be


productive, but the business environment for all local companies in the industry, their


suppliers, and firms in related industries will become less productive. This demonstrates


in particular the danger in arguments about the creation of "national champions" in an


industry in the home country in order to gain the scale to compete internationally. Unless


a firm is forced to compete at home, it will usually quickly lose its competitiveness


abroad. Local competition matters for productivity and productivity growth, even in


industries whose geographic scope is global.14


Note that no mention has been made of the ownership of the locally based firms.


This is because ownership has much less importance for externalities than the nature of


the activities undertaken in a given location. All firms in a given location must be


considered part of the cluster, not merely the domestic ones. Special weight for


competition derives from locally based entities that have significant development,


production, and other activities located in a nation. These offer far greater potential for


externalities than does competition from imports. Trade is not a full substitute for local


competition.


14 See, e.g., The Global Competitiveness Report 18 (various authors) (Geneva World Economic


Forum, 18); The Global Competitiveness Report 1 (various authors) (Geneva World Economic


Forum, 1); The Global Competitiveness Report 000 (various authors) (Geneva World Economic


Forum, 000).


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 11


III - THE GOALS AND TOOLS OF ANTITRUST POLICY


III.1. New Standard for Antitrust Productivity Growth


Since the role of competition is to increase a nation's standard of living and long-term


consumer welfare via rising productivity growth, the new standard for antitrust should be


productivity growth, rather than price/cost margins or profitability. All combinations or


practices scrutinized in antitrust should be subjected to the following question how will


they affect productivity growth? If a merger, joint venture, or other arrangement will


significantly enhance productivity growth, it is probably good for society and for


consumers (as well as the firms involved). Transactions with dubious benefits for


productivity growth, or those that offer only a one-time productivity benefit, are likely to


be net negatives for society if they pose any risk to the overall health of competition.


This is because competition is a primary determinant of future long-term productivity


growth.


How would the productivity growth standard affect antitrust? The current explicit and


implicit goals of U.S. antitrust policy fall roughly into the following hierarchy (see figure


5). Drawing on Welfare theory, the primary focus in U.S. antitrust for the last twenty


years has been on limiting price/cost margins or firm profitability (allocative inefficiency)


as the most important outcome for consumers. Market power is seen as giving firms the


ability to elevate prices and sustain high margins. Hence, limiting market power is the


major focus of attention.


Figure 5 Goals of Antitrust Policy


Traditional View Alternative View


Profitability / Price-Cost Margins


(allocative efficiency)


Cost reduction


(static efficiency)


Cost


(static efficiency)


Innovation


(dynamic efficiency)


Innovation


(dynamic efficiency)


Value improvement


(static productivity)


Profitability / Price-cost margin


standard


Productivity growth standard


Profitability / Price-Cost Margins


(allocative efficiency)


Second in importance in antitrust evaluations has been cost or technical efficiency.


The efficiency justification can be used to offset a finding of market power to elevate


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 1


margins. At the bottom of the current hierarchy is innovativeness, or the rate of dynamic


improvement. The effect of mergers or competitive practices on the overall rate of


innovation is usually only paid lip service.


If these three goals are tested against the productivity growth standard, it becomes


clear that the traditional hierarchy of goals should be reversed.


Because of its direct effect on productivity growth, the most important goal for


society is a healthy process of dynamic improvement, which requires innovations in


products, processes, or ways of managing. If the rate of dynamic improvement is


healthy, over time this dominates static technical and allocative efficiency concerns. For


example, a faster rate of innovation in new approaches overwhelms static economies of


scale in existing approaches, particularly in an age where knowledge-based competition


is the rule.


A productivity growth standard suggests that technical (static) efficiency should be


the second most important goal, but that it must be assessed with more subtlety. While


antitrust analysis tends to focus on cost justifications, equal attention should be paid to


product or service value. Roughly speaking, productivity is price times quantity divided


by the quantity of labor or capital involved. It can be divided into two distinct


components the prices that products command in the marketplace (which reflect value)


and the efficiency with which a unit of product can be produced. Thus, productivity is


enhanced not just by efficiency improvements, but also by improvements in product


quality, features, and services. Product variety is also an essential component of value,


giving customers more choices to better meet their particular needs.


High-value products provide the consumer with superior performance and features,


and therefore justify higher prices. With a focus on price/cost margins, however, high


prices are often seen as inherently undesirable for consumers. Higher prices should be a


danger sign in antitrust analysis only if they are not justified by rising customer value.


Limiting short-term price/cost margins or profitability is a dubious goal for antitrust.


Firm profitability is a good thing if it reflects truly superior products or significant


advantages in process technology or operating efficiency. It is a bad thing if it occurs in


the absence of a healthy rate of dynamic improvement. In a typical industry, average


price-cost margins and profitability will vary significantly among competitors, reflecting


varying levels of fundamental competitiveness.


Short-term consumer welfare measured by price, then, is a dubious goal on two


levels. First, it fails to measure true consumer welfare by ignoring product value.


Second, we care much more about the long-term trajectory of value, prices, and costs


than we do about consumer welfare in the short run or immediately after a merger.


Moreover, a productivity growth standard is entirely consistent with the language of the


main antitrust laws.


Benefits of a Productivity Growth Standard. Why is the productivity growth standard


different and important for antitrust? First, it is a positive standard that relates directly to


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 1


competitiveness, a nation's standard of living, and long-term consumer value, while


price/cost margins and technical efficiency are theoretically suspect. Productivity growth


is also more understandable and palatable to managers. Imagine how much more


constructive it would be for corporations and their attorneys to debate whether a merger


will boost productivity growth rather than continuing to debate the size of HHI.


Second, a productivity growth standard would shift antitrust away from a narrow


focus on static, short-term consumer welfare to a dynamic and more all-encompassing


view of competition and its benefits to consumers, firms, and society as whole. Defining


the goal of antitrust in terms of price/cost margins and profitability creates a zero-sum


game between firms and consumers. If consumers are to benefit from lower prices, firms


must earn lower profits. In contrast, a productivity growth standard raises no inevitable


trade-off. If productivity is growing, consumers can enjoy better products and/or lower


prices, companies can earn attractive returns on capital, and workers can enjoy rising


wages. A productivity growth standard, then, unites the perspectives of consumers,


workers, and companies. It embodies a positive sum rather than a zero-sum view of


competition. An approach to competition based on productivity growth will lead to


outcomes that benefit consumers far more than a shortsighted concern with static


profitability.


Finally, productivity growth addresses the reality of high-technology industries and


the so-called new economy by highlighting the fundamental importance of innovation.


While there are few true conceptual differences between the "new" and "old" economies,


the apparent mismatch between the static focus of antitrust and the rapid change in


technology-intensive industries has undermined antitrust's legitimacy. Since innovation


is the basic driver of productivity growth, promoting and protecting it should be central.


III.. Analysis of competition


How would the productivity standard be applied in practice? The best way to attain


maximal productivity growth in an industry is to ensure that industry competition is


healthy, since competition determines long-term productivity growth. It is possible to


measure past productivity growth in various ways, and we advocate that this become part


of antitrust analysis. However, predicting future productivity growth is more difficult.


Hence, there is a need for tools to assess the likely future health of competition, since this


will be the single most important factor in whether future gains in productivity will reach


their potential.


III..1. Measuring the health of industry competition Five Forces Analysis


To measure the health of competition in practice, we agree with those who believe


that seller concentration, the number of firms in a market, and profitability are not very


good indicators.15 They capture only part of a complex phenomenon and divert analyses


15 See, e.g., Ewing, supra note 1; Harris & Smith, supra note 1; Weller, supra note 1.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 14


of competition to much less productive debates over where to draw relevant market


boundaries. Instead, a broader approach is necessary. One such approach with


acceptance in business practice is the "five forces" analysis of the intensity of


competition.


The Five Forces Model.16 The five forces model is a dynamic approach to analyzing


industry structure, based on five competitive forces acting in an industry or sub-industry


threat of entry, threat of substitution, bargaining power of buyers, bargaining power of


suppliers, and rivalry among current competitors.17


This approach, with roots in industrial economics but moving beyond its narrower


interpretations, posits that competition in an industry is broader than price, and includes


product features, services, and processes. Competition is also seen as driven by many


influences. The five forces framework seeks to encompass all the important dimensions


of competition (see figure 6). It embodies the notion that competition is much broader


than just rivalry, where seller concentration (HHI) analysis is focused. Any of the five


forces can be significant in determining the health of competition, depending on the


particular industry. For example, the power of customers to push down price or pressure


improvements in service can be just as important to productivity growth as the number


and size distribution of competitors in the market.18


Five forces theory also argues that for any one of the competitive forces, the causes of


competitive intensity are multidimensional. In assessing the intensity of rivalry, for


example, seller concentration does have a role, although our interpretation would focus


more on the balance of competitors (the more balanced, the more rivalry). But the


intensity of rivalry also depends on a series of other dimensions, including, for example,


the industry cost structure. Where variable costs are low, strong pressures are created to


cut price in order to contribute to fixed cost. With such a cost structure, even a


concentrated industry can exhibit strong rivalry. Switching costs are another important


influence on rivalry. Where it is easy for customers to shift from one supplier to another,


the effect of concentration is mitigated.


The five forces methodology involves analysis on an industry-by-industry basis, and


does not rest on the determination of the relevant market. Every industry is different,


16 There is an extensive literature on five forces analysis that is beyond the scope of this article to


summarize here. The early references are M.E. Porter, Interbrand Choice, Strategy, and Bilateral


Market Power (176); M.E. Porter, Competitive Strategy Techniques for Analyzing Industries and


Competitors (180).


17 Brandenburger and Nalebuff have appropriately stressed the role of complementary products in


competition, and some have suggested complementary products as a sixth force (A. Brandenburger &


B. Nalebuff, Co-opetition, (16)). However, complementary products do not directly influence the


health of competition, but affect it indirectly through the influence of complements on the five forces.


The presence of a complementary product is neither good nor bad for competition per se. It depends


on how the complement influences, for example, barriers to entry or the power of the customer.


18 There is substantial empirical support for the importance of this broader set of industry attributes for


competition.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 15


both in terms of the relative influence of the forces and the array of drivers of each force.


This approach, which squares with actual industry competition, has been well accepted in


corporate practice and in management consulting firms to assess the nature of industry


competition.


Figure 6 Assessing the Health of Competition Five Forces Framework


Threat of Substitute


Products or


Services


Threat of New


Entrants


Rivalry Among


Existing


Competitors


Bargaining Power


of Suppliers


Bargaining Power


of Buyers


Source M.E. Porter, Competitive Strategy Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors 187


(180).


Many of the elements of the five forces approach have been known to or used in


economics for a long time. Also, many of the considerations raised in the five forces


model appear somewhere in current merger analysis. Five forces analysis is different in


how, when and why the model is applied. Current antitrust analysis first determines the


relevant geographic and product market, then uses its tools to analyze competitive effects.


Current analysis starts with seller concentration as the principal metric. Other


considerations are brought in, both only later and secondarily. Five forces analysis, on


the other hand, avoids the first step by going straight to analyzing competitive effects in


any and all submarkets deemed relevant by customers and competitors. It views seller


concentration as only one and not the most important determinant of rivalry. It brings in


all five forces as equally important. Finally, it does not rely heavily on price and quantity


as the principal indicators of welfare.


By assessing competition beyond existing rivals, the need is reduced for debates on


where to draw industry boundaries, or the relevant market in antitrust terms. Any


definition of a market is essentially a choice of where to draw the line between


established competitors and substitute products, between existing firms and potential


entrants, and between existing firms and suppliers and buyers. If these influences on


competition are all recognized, and their relative impact assessed, as they are in five


forces analysis, then where the lines are actually drawn becomes more or less irrelevant


to strategy formulation and, I suggest, the antitrust analysis of competition. Latent


sources of competition will not be overlooked, nor will key dimensions of competition.


The need to determine the relevant market is eliminated.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 16


While there is a systematic approach to market definition defined in the Merger


Guidelines, it begins with the questionable premise that a single market definition is a


meaningful concept. Moreover, the approach to market definition relies heavily on price


effects which are an incomplete measure of social benefit, not to mention a largely shortterm


and static one.


Productivity Growth and Forms of Competition. The multidimensional nature of


rivalry is important for understanding the link between rivalry and productivity. Some


forms of rivalry are more productivity-enhancing than others, and thus are more valued


socially.


For example, one can array types of rivalry along a spectrum including the following


(see also figure 7)


1. Competition based on imitation/price discounting


. Competition based on strategic positioning.


The first type of competition is on operational effectiveness, or the extent to which


companies approach best practices in areas such as production processes, technologies,


marketing methods, and management techniques. The second, and more fundamental to


success in an advanced economy, is competition to create different value propositions for


customers, a function of the degree to which companies have distinctive strategies.


Figure 7 Rivalry and Productivity Growth


Imitation and Price


Discounting


Strategic


Rivalry


• Homogeneous products/services


at low prices


• Multiple, different value


propositions


e.g., features, services,


processes, price levels


• Different approaches to design,


operations, marketing, etc.


"Zero sum competition" "Positive sum competition"


• Incremental cost improvements • Potential for fundamental process


improvements


• Lots of customer choice


• Expanded market


• Little true customer choice


• Imitate best practices


Assessing the two according to the productivity growth standard gives very different


results. Imitation-based competition leads to similar products among rivals and strong


pressures for price discounting. Strategic competition occurs when rivals pursue different


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 17


value propositions some firms offer low prices producing stripped down products, others


have higher prices but provide better service, while still others concentrate on various


segments of the market, tailoring their products and value chains accordingly.


If price/cost margins are used as the metric of social benefit, then imitation and price


discounting seem ideal. Customers get the benefit of low prices, and the ability to play


one company against others. From a productivity growth standpoint, however, this form


of competition may lead to slower dynamic improvement. Competition on strategic


positioning can foster increased variety and greater choices for customers in terms of the


product that best meets their needs, not to mention more innovation in products and


processes. In strategic competition, markets often expand as new needs are met and new


customers are drawn into the market. It is important to note that internationally


competitive, advanced nations have more innovation- and differentiation-based


competition, while less competitive nations tend to compete on imitation and price.1


This analysis leads to the controversial conclusion that holding down profitability is


the wrong issue for society. Profitability has a contingent relationship with productivity


growth. The American software industry is far more profitable than the software


industries in other countries, but it is also far more productive and internationally


competitive. High profits are fine, provided competition is healthy and there are strong


pressures for dynamic improvement. The productivity growth standard, then, casts new


light on how we assess competition. It reveals the importance of understanding the kind


of competition a nation should really be looking for.


III... Measuring the health of local competition The Diamond framework


As has been argued, it is not sufficient to consider only industry competition


generally. We must also have a means of gauging the health of local competition. Here,


one such approach to assessing the potential productivity of a local business environment


is embodied in the so-called diamond framework.0


The productivity of a national business environment can be modeled using four


interacting components that can be depicted as a diamond (see figure 8). These are


1. Context for firm strategy and rivalry


. Factor (input) conditions


. Demand conditions


1 For supporting statistical findings, see Porter, supra note 5. Results are similar in previous years'


reports. See the full The Global Competitiveness Reports for 18, 1 & 000; and Porter, Takeuchi


& Sakakibara, supra note 7.


0 M.E. Porter, The Competitive Advantage of Nations (10). For the empirical application of Diamond


theory to 5 countries, see The Global Competitiveness Report 000, at 40-58, 101-1, including data


definitions and sources at -. For 18 and 1, see The Global Competitiveness Report for


those years. For an extensive empirical application of Diamond theory to Japan, see Porter, Takeuchi


& Sakakibara, supra note 7.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 18


4. Related and supporting industries


Like the five forces, this framework aims to capture the many influences on the


productivity of the local business environment in an industry or overall. Rivalry among


locally based competitors is not only important to productivity growth directly but also


creates positive externalities for the local business environment. A group of competing


local rivals helps customers become more knowledgeable and competitive, encourages


more specialized suppliers to develop, and enhances the local supply of high-quality,


specialized inputs. This gives rise to a series of new questions that must be addressed in


analyzing the impact on competition of a merger or other competitive practice, which will


be discussed below.


Figure 8 The Externalities of Rivalry Locational Determinants of Productivity


and Productivity Growth


Related and


Supporting


Industries


Related and


Supporting


Industries


• Open and vigorous competition


among locally based rivals


• Rivalry among locally-based competitors is not only important directly but also creates positive


externalities for the local business environment


Context for


Firm


Strategy


and Rivalry


Context for


Firm


Strategy


and Rivalry


Factor


(Input)


Conditions


Factor


(Input)


Conditions


• Sophisticated and demanding


local customer(s) whose needs


anticipate those elsewhere


• Unusual local demand in


specialized segments that can be


served globally


• Presence of capable, locally based


suppliers and firms in related fields


Demand


Conditions


Demand


Conditions


• A local context that encourages


investment and sustained upgrading


• Availability of highquality


and specialized


inputs


Source M.E. Porter, The Competitive Advantage of Nations 1 (10).


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 1


IV. EVALUATING MERGERS AND JOINT VENTURES


IV.1. Why mergers should be of particular concern for antitrust


Where productivity growth is the central goal of antitrust, it becomes clear that


mergers should be treated with special caution compared to other corporate growth


strategies. This is true for five reasons


First, mergers raise almost inevitable issues for the health of competition by removing


independent competitors from the market. The question is not whether there is a risk to


competition, but how much. This risk stems from the potential lessening of competitive


pressure among firms in the industry, the potential reduction in product choice and


variety, and the reduction in the number of different approaches being pursued to


product/process development and hence the likelihood of innovation.


Second, a merger requires no "skill, foresight, and industry,"1 only financial


resources. It demands no new strategy, and yields no automatic productivity


improvements. By contrast, introducing a new product, changing a distribution model, or


building a new plant are far more likely to boost productivity. Society, then, should be


biased in favor of independent company actions over mergers.


Third, the empirical evidence is striking that mergers have a low success rate. A wide


range of studies finds that most mergers do not meet expectations, and most of the profits


are captured by the seller, not the buyer.


Fourth, the strategy literature suggests that smaller, focused acquisitions are more


likely to improve productivity than mergers among leaders. When a large company buys


a small company and integrates it into its strategy, major productivity gains are possible.


Mergers among large companies appear to rarely yield such benefits, though they may


produce reduction in joint overhead and eliminate major competitors from a market.


Fifth, there are strong financial market pressures favoring mergers over other growth


strategies. These arise at least in part from agency problems afflicting both investment


managers compensated based on near term stock price appreciation, and company


executives given incentives with stock options.


Finally, accounting rules make merger a vehicle for distorted performance


measurement, creating artificial pressures for companies to merge.


We cannot assume that a merger will be efficient and profitable just because


companies propose it. Companies make mistakes. Every merger needs to be weighed


against the productivity growth standard. Indeed, a positive antitrust policy based on


1 U.S. v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.d 416, 40 (d Cir. 145) (Hand, J.).


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 0


productivity growth might actually enhance both the performance of companies and


consumer welfare, which would be even better for society.


IV.. Towards a New Merger Evaluation Process


In dealing with a proposed merger, the primary concern for antitrust should be how


the merger, if allowed, would affect productivity growth. We must consider both likely


future productivity growth in the industry, as well as the near term productivity impact on


the merged firms. The effect of the merger on the health of competition will be central to


its likely productivity impact, net of any direct positive productivity growth impacts that


can be convincingly demonstrated.


Three Levels of Analysis. In analyzing a merger or joint venture then, the three basic


levels of analysis needed are


1. Merger significance and baseline productivity growth analysis.


. The effect of the transaction on the health of competition using the five forces


and the diamond framework in all significant markets and submarkets that are


relevant based on industry and customer practice.


. A risk/reward analysis of the merger, where its effect on the health of


competition is weighed against proposed direct benefits using the productivity


growth standard.


IV..1. Significance and Baseline Productivity Growth Analysis


This analysis can be broken up into three principal tasks (1) identifying the set of


relevant markets and submarkets and the relevant geographic area; () determining


whether or not the firm meets a predetermined combined market share cutoff in the


relevant markets and submarkets; and if so, () establishing the baseline productivity


performance of the industry and the firms party to the transaction.


Step 1. Rather than going through the lengthy and controversial exercise of trying to


define the market affected by a merger, this new merger evaluation process is applied to


all relevant markets and submarkets. There are usually a number of economically


relevant market definitions, and each of these is considered. In determining plausible


markets or submarkets, three practical criteria can be helpful


1. How the industry itself defines submarkets


. How consumers segment the market


. Whether there is a competitor focused on the submarket (i.e., a focused


company dedicated only to serving the submarket, which suggests that it is a


viable array of products, varieties, and customers with distinct needs)


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 1


Once all plausible markets and submarkets have been identified, the geographic area


over which local externalities apply is determined. Note that the relevant geographic area


is not based on the geography of sales, but on the externalities in production. The starting


assumption is that the geographic unit is the national economy. In some industries, the


relevant geographic area can be smaller than a nation. Clusters occur within a region or


metropolitan area. In some cases, externalities can cross national borders of immediate


neighboring countries.


Step . To invest the resources required to investigate a particular merger or joint


venture, some significance threshold is inevitable. We advocate a relatively low


minimum market share threshold of, say, 5 percent combined share in any submarket


(discussed below). Such a threshold will conserve resources and screen out transactions


where the probability of material impact on competition is small.


There is no contradiction between this cut-off level and our rejection of seller


concentration as a measure of market power. We use concentration solely as a


significance indicator. A merger involving a small portion of any submarket is unlikely


to raise important antitrust issues. Above this threshold, we do not treat higher share


mergers differently than ones with somewhat lower shares.


Step . This step establishes the baseline, historical industry and company


performance in terms of productivity growth and robustness of rivalry. For this


we look at direct measures of productivity, such as revenue per hour of labor,


value added per unit of capital, etc. In order to test the vitality of rivalry in the


industry, the fluctuation of market shares in all relevant markets and submarkets


are examined. Needed data would be requested in the premerger notification


process.


If the affected industry has registered weak productivity growth in the past


relative to the economy-wide or industry averages, or if the industry has exhibited


limited rivalry historically, this should raise the level of scrutiny by antitrust


authorities. If the firms involved in the merger have registered weak or average


productivity growth performance relative to the industry, this would raise the


level of scrutiny. If substantial past market share fluctuations have involved the


party firms, this would raise the level of scrutiny as well because the merger may


be an attempt to stabilize competition. The baseline performance step is a


retrospective analysis, providing grounding for the prospective analyses described


below.


IV... Assessing the Health of Competition


The next level of analysis is to predict the effects of the merger on long term


productivity growth by determining its effects on the health of competition. Five forces


analysis is used to measure the health of industry competition in all relevant markets and


submarkets, while the diamond framework is used to measure its likely effect on the


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page


health of local competition. If both lead to the conclusion that there is no material


negative effect on competition, the merger or joint venture would be approved. If either


analysis raises questions, the process would move to the next stage.


Five Forces Analysis. Here the effect of the merger or joint venture on


barriers to entry, rivalry, customer power, substitution, and the power of the


suppliers would be explored. The analysis should be conducted for all relevant


segments and submarkets.


FigureMerger Effect on the Health of Industry Competition Five Forces


Analysis


• Concentration and balance


• Industry growth


• Fixed (or storage costs/


value added


• Intermittent overcapacity


• Product differences


• Brand identity


Determinants of Supplier Power


• Cost relative to total purchases in the industry


• Differentiation of inputs


• Impact of inputs on cost or differentiation


• Switching to a new supplier


• Presence of substitute inputs


• Supplier concentration


• Importance of volume to supplier


• Threat of forward integration relative to threat of


backward integration by firms in the industry


Threat of Substitute


Products or Services


Threat of New


Entrants


Rivalry Among


Existing Competitors Bargaining Power


of Suppliers


Bargaining Power


of Buyers


Bargaining Leverage


• Buyer concentration


vs firm concentration


• Buyer volume


• Buyer switching


costs relative to firm


switching costs


• Buyer information


• Ability to backward


integrate


• Substitute products


• Pull-through


Determinants of Substitution Threat


• Relative price performance of substitutes


• Switching costs


• Buyer propensity to substitute


Price Sensitivity


• Price/total purchases


• Product differences


• Brand identity


• Impact on quality/


performance


• Buyer profits


• Decisionmakers'


incentives


• Switching costs


• Informational complexity


• Diversity of competitors


• Corporate stakes


• Exit barriers


Rivalry Determinants


• Economies of scale


• Proprietary product differences


• Brand identity


• Switching costs


• Capital requirements


• Access to distribution


• Proprietary learning curve


• Access to necessary inputs


• Proprietary low-cost product design


• Government policy


• Expected retaliation


Entry Barriers/Mobility Barriers


Each of the five forces is affected by a series of drivers (see figure ). Every one of


these factors must be assessed in turn. The starting point is to establish the level of each


driver and the direction in which it is moving (i.e. increasing, decreasing, or stable)


before the merger, then determine whether and how the merger will affect these. Often


the effect of the merger on a particular driver can be quantified precisely. At the very


least it is possible to ascertain whether the effect is positive, negative, or neutral, and


whether the effect is likely to be significant or modest. A particular merger, for example,


might have a strong tendency to raise barriers to entry. One is normally able to estimate


the increase in minimum scale. The size of the increase would be weighed against shifts


in other forces. If all other things remain equal, the merger's effect would be judged


negative. If buyer power or the substitution threat was rising, however, the analyst would


assess whether the magnitude of the effect was offsetting.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page


The role of "Concentration and Balance" in rivalry may appear similar to market


share analysis. However, even here there are substantial differences. First, seller


concentration is only one of the many determinants of rivalry. Second, we are mostly


interested in the balance between competitors and how this affects rivalry, not shares per


se. Third, we are less interested in market shares than in the fluctuation of market shares.


Finally, the types of rivalry prevalent currently and likely in the future are considered


with their differing effects on the growth in productivity.


The five forces approach offers several advantages in evaluating merger or joint


venture transactions in contrast to using seller concentration and HHI analysis. First, the


broader analysis is more intuitively appealing as a representation of competition. Seller


concentration and HHI analysis is arcane and can be arbitrary. It is prone to attempts at


manipulation and gaming.


Second, five forces analysis is based on a rich conception of competition, which is


multidimensional and not based only on price. Managers know that seller concentration


is not the dominant influence on competition. As has been discussed, price competition


may not be the most beneficial form of rivalry for productivity growth.


Third, the five forces framework can and should be readily applied to any and all


market definitions. It can be applied to the industry as a whole, and to any segment (a


segment can be a particular customer group, subset of product varieties, or combination


of the two). Barriers to entry into a segment, for example, may be higher or lower than


barriers to entering other segments; and substitute products often vary by segment as


well. The definition of the industry can be expanded to include substitutes, customers


who are partially backward integrated, or some potential entrants. With five forces


methodology, it matters less where industry boundaries are drawn because the framework


encompasses all the important influences on competition.


Fourth, five forces analysis is very fact-intensive, and its conclusions depend on the


particular fact pattern in an industry rather than generalizations embodied in HHI or seller


concentration cutoffs. Every industry is unique, and requires analysis of its own


particular characteristics. The five forces framework can be seen as an expert system; it


takes the facts of a particular case and translates them into the implications for


competition.


Finally, the five forces framework also allows an assessment of both near-term and


long-term effects on competition. In industry competition, it is rare that the first move is


the end state. When a merger takes place, for example, it can trigger mergers by others.


A good analysis considers what could happen next, and weighs its consequences for


industry structure. Concentration analysis, in contrast, tends to be short term and static.


It might be argued that many of the considerations revealed in five forces analysis are


considered in the existing merger evaluation process by skilled practitioners. This is


certainly true, but this proves rather than argues against its usefulness. Existing merger


analysis is hamstrung by an unclear and questionable central goal (limiting short-term


price-cost margins), and the process is built on HHI, a questionable measure of


competition. Other considerations come in only later, and as adjustments and balancing


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 4


arguments. This indirect approach seems less reliable in weighing the issues than a


frontal approach. Moreover, since these additional considerations are not clearly stated in


the Merger Guidelines, they are not transparent to companies, making the entire process


appear arbitrary.


Current merger evaluation is also compromised by its reliance on short-term price and


quantity analysis. The result is a sort of false precision, in which tools like merger


simulation seem to be exact but assume a stylized model of competition based solely on


price and quantity and say little about what will occur in the long run.


Performing five forces analysis requires significant effort in terms of data collection


and analysis, which some argue would pose challenges to antitrust authorities with


limited resources. However, a skilled practitioner can reach informed judgements based


on a modest number of industry interviews and secondary sources, and the approach


allows effort to be quickly focused on the most important issues. Moreover, the current


merger evaluation process involves enormous effort in determining and litigating relevant


market and concentration. The proposed merger evaluation process may in fact prove


less burdensome for antitrust authorities than current practice and the effort involved


more fruitful in terms of understanding the true competition issues facing the affected


industry.


Diamond Analysis. We apply the diamond analysis to determine the effect of the


merger on the productivity of the local business environment.


Figure 10 Merger Effect on the Health of Local Competition Diamond Analysis


Context for


Firm


Strategy


and Rivalry


Context for


Firm


Strategy


and Rivalry


Related and


Supporting


Industries


Related and


Supporting


Industries


Factor


(Input)


Conditions


Factor


(Input)


Conditions


• How will the merger affect the


competitiveness and


innovative ability of local


customers?


• How does the merger


affect the number of


locally based rivals?


Demand


Conditions


Demand


Conditions


• How is the merger likely to affect


the quantity and quality of


specialized inputs available to


firms locally?


human resources


specialized capital providers


physical infrastructure


administrative infrastructure


information infrastructure


scientific and technological


infrastructure


• How will the merger affect the


vitality of locally based


supplier industries?


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 5


Figure 10 highlights the questions to be considered. For example, a reduction of local


competition due to a merger can hurt competition and productivity in customer industries.


Cut off from close relationships with independent, locally based vendors, customers can


become less productive and or their ability to innovate can decline.


Diamond analysis points again to how misleading a focus on seller concentration can


be compared to a focus on productivity growth. Global industry definition is invariably


invoked to minimize the concentration effects of mergers. However, if competition is


diminished in the local market, the adverse consequences for productivity can be


substantial. While there can be static efficiency benefits of a merger between large


national rivals that are often emphasized, these tend to be one-shot benefits that are less


significant than the consequences of the merger for productivity growth.


Taking into account externalities in local competition leads one to be particularly


wary of a merger between a leading international company and a leading domestic


company, especially when the domestic company will be integrated and important


activities will be moved to other locations, thereby diminishing potential local


externalities. International companies seeking to acquire a local company should be


encouraged to acquire a smaller competitor. This would reduce the risk of diminishing


local rivalry, and may actually increase it.


IV... Direct Productivity Growth Offsets


If it is determined that there is a significant potential adverse effect on the health of


competition in the short or long term in either industry competition or local competition,


the direct effect of the merger (or joint venture) on productivity growth would be


assessed. Key questions would include the following Are there clear and significant


productivity growth benefits that can be demonstrated? Are these productivity gains


ongoing or one time? How likely are they to occur? Here, the parties would be expected


to demonstrate fundamental and lasting productivity growth benefits along the lines


discussed below. A risk/reward analysis would then determine whether the merger or


joint venture is approved by the government, or lawful under the antitrust laws. Clear


productivity growth benefits from the merger or joint venture would be necessary to


outweigh the threat to competition that the merger entailed.


Potential direct productivity benefits should be evaluated according to the hierarchy


depicted in figure 11. Productivity enhancement consists of both product value (which is


usually reflected in price), and efficiency (or cost). Both are important, and priority must


be given to dynamic improvements over static ones.


Companies often tout the fact that mergers reduce costs, but what they really mean in


many cases is that the merger will allow elimination of redundant corporate overhead.


This form of cost reduction is marginal for productivity growth because it is a one-time


benefit and does not affect the inherent operating cost of producing and delivering a


product or service. A merger that leads to ongoing savings in the actual operating costs of


the business is much more attractive in meeting the productivity growth standard. A


merger that creates greater scale over which to amortize largely fixed costs such as media


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 6


advertising falls somewhere in between. The productivity growth standard therefore


casts new light on the efficiency justification for mergers and other practices.


Figure 11 Hierarchy of Productivity Enhancement


Cost Buyer Value


• Customer satisfaction is an important


sign of healthy competition


I. Reduce operating costs


II. Amortize fixed/semi-fixed costs


(e.g., advertising, service locations)


III. Eliminate redundant corporate


overhead


I. Improve product/service quality


and features


II. Increase marketing and distribution


strength


III. Enhance brand identity


In addition, post-merger reductions in operating costs that involve a rationalization of


product lines may actually involve a reduction in product variety. The improvement on


the cost side results in deterioration on the value side, which must be considered in the


overall assessment.


On the value side, mergers with clear and demonstrable benefits for the quality and


features of the actual product or service should be favored. These are likely to be far


more meaningful to productivity and productivity growth than those that only improve


marketing or strengthen distribution. The latter benefits usually come at the price of


higher barriers to entry and reductions in productivity growth over time.


Productivity growth analysis focuses on the long-term trajectory of product value and


cost, not only on perturbations to current productivity. One-shot benefits to productivity


are overwhelmed if a merger or other arrangement risks lowering the rate of productivity


growth.


The threshold for offsetting direct productivity benefits would be higher if


1. The merger produced a dominant firm;


. Past productivity performance of the industry or party firms was weak;


. The party firms have been direct and vigorous rivals.


Justifications based on network effects and Schumpeterian competition for the


market. Opponents of strong antitrust enforcement frequently argue that pervasive


network effects dominate the so-called new economy, making large, dominant firms


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 7


unavoidable in many "high-tech" industries. This argument is sometimes used to defend


mergers that create a dominant firm, since consumers are expected to benefit from


dealing with a larger network.


Network effects exist when an industry is marked by economies of scale in


consumption, that is, when a product or service is more valuable to an individual


customer the more total customers there are. Examples include telephone service, fax


machines, e-mail, etc. Network effects can and should be analyzed in context of the five


forces, for instance when discussing barriers to entry, or the nature of rivalry.


Network effects are not new, and there is little systematic evidence that they are more


pervasive in high-tech industries than traditional ones. Furthermore, network effects are


often not proprietary to individual firms, and are self-limiting to the extent that customer


needs vary within the industry. Substantial network effects large enough to support a


dominant position appear to occur only in a very small subset of industries. There is no


need for mergers as a growth strategy if there are true proprietary network effects. Firms


should be required to grow internally instead. In the rare case of proprietary network


effects leading to a dominant firm that is able to block entry, antitrust policy should


require interoperability or an open standard, unless a compelling case can be made that


keeping the standard proprietary leads to faster growth in productivity.


In parallel to the discussion of network effects, the claim is often made that these


same high-tech industries are characterized by Schumpeterian competition, in which


frequent drastic innovations disrupt the market, creating new winner-take-all races. The


presumed high frequency of these innovations is asserted to prevent currently dominant


companies from establishing long term monopoly positions. Therefore, it is argued,


antitrust should not intervene in high tech industries with large dominant firms, since


corrective forces will work to overturn them naturally.


A Schumpeterian focus on innovation is essential, and highly supportive of a move to


productivity growth as an antitrust standard. However, using Schumpeter as a


justification for ignoring anticompetitive behavior or for allowing mergers among leading


competitors dramatically underestimates the time between market-disrupting occurrences,


even in high tech industries. In truth, drastic innovations in industries occur only once


every few decades, so that dominant positions create substantial costs to productivity


growth and to society. It should also be noted that mergers are anti-Schumpeterian. Far


from reflecting true innovations, they tend to entrench established companies and temper


the rate of innovation occurring in an industry. Therefore, the above argument is


spurious in attempting to justify mergers.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 8


IV.. The Process Summarized


Figure 1 provides a summary of this merger evaluation process.


Figure 1 Merger Approval Process


Significant adverse effect on competition


in either industry or local competition


Direct Offsetting Productivity Gains Specific to the Merged Firms


Significance and Baseline Industry Performance


Merger Effect on the Health of Industry Competition


(analysis done for all relevant markets and submarkets)


Merger Effect on the Health of Local Competition


No material effect on competition


Merger approved


Gains clearly outweigh effects on


competition


Gains do not outweigh effects on


competition


Merger approved


Merger rejected, unless


substantially modified


I.


II.


III.


Threshold level of scrutiny set


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page


V. MERGER CASE STUDY


Figure 1 offers a brief case study of this analytical process, based on a merger


between two offshore drilling companies. In this industry, firms operate highly capitalintensive


drilling units that cost up to $500 million apiece. The merger of companies A


and B would create a combined company with the highest overall share of the industry,


and a dominant share in one large, important segment. On the surface, the merger looks


troubling. Using the standard approach of defining submarkets and calculating HHI, it


fails.


Figure 1 Case Study Offshore Drilling


Merger of Company A and Company B


• Significantly higher combined share of most markets than the next largest rival


• "Dominant" share in ultra deepwater segment


Five Forces Analysis


• Customers are powerful


• Undifferentiated product with an ugly cost structure


• Low entry barriers


• Highly competitive industry overall


• Ultra deepwater segment serves the most powerful customers


• Customers, through long-term contracts and financing, can readily put new competitors


(who operate in other segments) into the ultra deepwater business


• Little or no risk to competition


Externalities (Location) Analysis


• Numerous U.S. rivals remain


• Little effect on Houston supplier base


• No stronger cluster exists anywhere else in the world


• Little or no risk to cluster externalities


Five forces analysis reveals, however, that customers in the industry are very


powerful, major oil companies. They can put new rivals into business and, through longterm


contracts, can also cause new drilling units to be constructed. Rigs are essentially


undifferentiated and have high fixed costs. Low marginal costs make the business prone


to deep price discounting. Assets can be easily moved from one geographic market to


another. Although it would seem that the high asset costs create formidable barriers to


entry, since powerful customers can use long-term contracts to put companies into new


segments and rig technology is widely available, actual entry barriers are modest. The


segment in which the merger would yield a dominant share also proves to be the segment


with the most powerful customers.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 0


The merger also raises few concerns for locational externalities. Post-merger,


numerous U.S.-based offshore drillers would still be present. New entry remains


feasible. There is little likely effect on suppliers or other Houston-based institutions.


Moreover, there is no other location in the world with a close to comparable critical mass


of rivals, suppliers, and other institutions.


An analysis beginning with HHI could certainly reach the same conclusion.


However, there can be much wasted effort and unproductive discussion. Also, antitrust


lawyers are drawn to concentrate on the HHI analysis because it is highly specific and


comes first in the process, with other subsequent "considerations" far less transparent.


To implement the five forces and locational approaches, a body of examples and


guidelines for quantification and weighing various factors will be needed. This can be


developed in subsequent papers, drawing on the large body of experience in corporate


and economic development practice.


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page 1


VI. ADDITIONAL U.S. ANTITRUST ISSUES


In the United States, the role of antitrust in limiting anticompetitive mergers and joint


ventures that threaten industry productivity growth could be reinforced by a number of


other public policy changes. One is eliminating pooling of interest, a policy which is


currently being implemented. Pooling-of-interests accounting obscures the financial


consequences of a merger, and allows companies to report post-merger profit


improvements that are misleading.


Stricter rules on merger write-offs and restructuring charges would also limit


uneconomic mergers. If the purchase price of a merger can be partly written off, the


ongoing reported ROI can be artificially high. Since companies must invest the full


purchase price to acquire a company, the full purchase price should appear as an


investment on the books. Restructuring charges and write-offs are artificial adjustments


that do not make the amount of the investment any different.


Third, new reporting requirements that mandated ongoing disclosure of total equity


investment before write-offs would produce a better understanding of true return on


shareholder investment. A company that generates improving returns by writing off a


substantial part of its investment will be recognized for what it is, a company that has not


used shareholder capital very well.


Finally, a comprehensive data set on mergers and their longevity and outcomes would


be useful and potentially revealing. In a 187 paper, I examined the merger history of a


sample of companies back to World War II, and calculated the share of mergers that were


liquidated or divested. This proportion turned out to be well over 50 percent of all


transactions. Data such as this would sensitize managers and investors alike of the risks


of these transactions.


Today, an unhealthy situation has been created in which distorted reporting leads


shareholders to believe that bad mergers are good. This then leads managers to pursue


mergers with no real productivity benefits, and sets up a contest with antitrust officials to


get such transactions approved.


M.E. Porter, "From Competitive Advantage to Corporate Strategy," Harvard Business Review, May-


June 187, at 4. See also Scherer, "Some Principles for Post-Chicago Antitrust Analysis," 5 CWRU


Law Rev. 5, 11-1 (00) ("study after study" has shown that the acquiring company's stock price


"decline[d] by impressive and statistically significant magnitudes in the one to three years" after the


merger; see also Frank &Sidel, "Firms That Lived by the Deal Are Now Sinking by the Dozens" A1


(June 6, 00).


DRAFT VERSION 07//0


Page


VII. CONCLUSION


The current approach to antitrust rests on questionable and often unclear foundations,


giving its numerous critics reason to condemn it as unnecessary or, at worse, harmful.


However, antitrust is more crucial than ever in an economy characterized by dynamic


competition. By adopting a productivity growth standard, antitrust would better link the


health of competition to not only consumer welfare but to competitiveness and national


policy, making the rationale for vigorous competition much more convincing.


The productivity growth approach aims to define an explicit hierarchy of goals for


antitrust law and policy, and a framework that leads companies contemplating mergers to


confront the issues that are important for society, firms, and their shareholders, as well as


for consumers. The pressing need is that corporate discussions with government and the


bases for litigation be focused on the right issues. We should not be debating the size of


the company, the market definition, nor what the "correct" HHI should be. We should be


debating the merger or joint venture's impact on productivity growth and on the health of


competition, using tools that capture the richness of competition and match with the


reality faced by firms.


This new approach would better align the interests of consumers, companies,


workers, and the overall economy, as sustained productivity growth is the desired


outcome for all parties. Today's antitrust is too often a contest between firms and the


government; a broader, richer analysis of competition based on productivity growth


standard could change that. Indeed, the productivity growth standard demonstrates the


surprising underlying symmetry between companies' interests, consumers' interests, and


society's interests. A strong antitrust policy that correctly articulated this symmetry


would encounter far less resistance than current policy. Even if all aspects of the new


approach are not adopted, there is an urgent need to move toward reversing the current


hierarchy of goals in antitrust and adopting a productivity growth focus.


Please note that this sample paper on analysis five forces of framework is for your review only. In order to eliminate any of the plagiarism issues, it is highly recommended that you do not use it for you own writing purposes. In case you experience difficulties with writing a well structured and accurately composed paper on analysis five forces of framework, we are here to assist you.Your cheap custom college paper on analysis five forces of framework will be written from scratch, so you do not have to worry about its originality.


Order your authentic assignment and you will be amazed at how easy it is to complete a quality custom paper within the shortest time possible!